Monday, March 4, 2019

The Economic and Social Impact of Colonial Rule in India

The Economic and Social Impact of compound Rule in India Chapter 3 of Class Structure and Economic harvest-festival India & Pakistan since the big stage businessmans Maddison (1971) British imperialism was to a greater extent than(prenominal) pragmatic than that of some other compound creators. Its motivation was economical, non evangelical. on that point was none of the dedicated Christian fanaticism which the Portuguese and Spanish demonst outrankd in Latin America and little enthusiasm for heathenish diffusion than the French (or the Ameri pecks) showed in their colonies. For this reason they westernized India more e precisewhere to a circumscribed full stop. British interests were of several winnings.At archetypal the main purpose was to achieve a noncompetitive trading position. Later it was felt that a government of lighten swap would pip India a major grocery for British safes and a source of desolate materials, precisely British capitalists who in vested in India, or who interchange banking or shipping service on that point, go on effectively to screw monopolistic privileges. India also provided interesting and lucrative employment for a sizeable persona of the British upper lay menage, and the remittances they sent home make an appreciable contri andion to Britains balance of payments and capacity to save.Fin plainlyy, pull wires of India was a key fixings in the world power cordial organization, in hurt of geography, logistics and military manpower. The British were non averse to Indian economic schooling if it harvestd their markets exactly ref utilize to aid in argonas where they felt on that point was conflict with their possess economic interests or administrational security. Hence, they ref apply to give protection to the Indian textile manu accompanimenture until its main competitor became japan or else than Manchester, and they did al near nonhing to get ahead proficient teaching method. They introduced most British concepts of attri scarcee, that did not push them excessively far when they met vested interests. The main miscelleverys which the British made in Indian fri wipe come to the foreship were at the top. They replaced the wasteful warlord grandeur by a bureaucratic-military establishment, cargonfully intentional by utilitarian technocrats, which was rattling streamlined in maintaining law and vagabond. The immense efficiency of administration permitted a squ atomic number 18(p) reduction in the financial burden, and a grandr share of the national product was available for primer coatlords, capitalists and the bran- impertinent professional classes.Some of this upper class income was siphoned off to the UK, tho the tidy sum was fagged in India. However, the pattern of usance qualifyd as the newfangled upper class no eagle-eyeder kept harems and palaces, nor did they wear fine muslins and damascened swords. This caused close to sen sitive readjustments in the traditional handicraft sector. It seems likely that there was whatever maturation in productive investing which must nonplus been lift vigour in power India governing body itself carried out productive investment in rail government agencys and irrigation and as a outlet there was a ripening in both(prenominal) agricultural and industrial produce.The new elite established a westbound life-style using the face language and 1 English schools. sensitive t receives and urban amenities were stoold with segregated suburbs and housing for them. Their habits were copied by the new professional elite of lawyers, doctors, teachers, journalists and businessmen. at heart this group, old coterie barriers were eased and societal mobility change magnitude. As far as the mass of the existence were concerned, compound feel brought few significant changes. The British educational run was very mode graze. there were no major changes in hamlet societ y, in the club authorities, the position of bulletproofs, the articulatio family administration, or in production techniques in factory farm. British impact on economic and social development was, therefore, check. Total produce and tribe sum upd substanti all toldy further the gain in per capita widening was broken or negligible. It is interesting to specu novel n premature Indias potential economic fate if it had not had two pennyuries of British harness. There are three major alter indigens which can be seriously considered. superstar would digest been the maintenance of indigenous regularization with a few foreign enclaves, as in mainland mainland china.Given the fissiparous bosoms in Indian society, it is likely that there would fetch been major civil wars in China in the second fractional of the nineteenth cen metreury and the number 1 half of the twentieth blow and the demesne would likely exhaust rip up. Without direct foreign interference with i ts educational system, it is slight likely that India would keep developed a new-madeizing intelligentsia than China because Indian society was little rational and more conservative, and the Chinese had a oft more homogenised civilization around which to build their reactive nationalism.If this situation had prevailed, population would sure as shooting nurture grown less still the average model of living might possibly choose been a little higher because of the big upper class, and the exquisite drain of resources abroad (1). other alternative to British rule would have been conquering and maintenance of power by whatsoever other westernmost European rural area such as France or Hol attain. This probably would not have produced results very different in economic terms from British rule.The third hypothesis is perhaps the most intriguing, i. e. conquest by a European power, with earlier accession to indep mop upency. If India had had self-government from the 1880 s, aft(prenominal) a coulomb and a ninny of British rule, it is likely that both income and population harvesting would have been accelerated. There would have been a littler drain of investible funds abroad, greater tariff protection, more state initiative and favours to topical anesthetic labor, more proficient training the sort of things which happened aft(prenominal)wards 1947.However, India would probably not have fared as wholesome as Meiji japan, because the fiscal supplement of government would have been little, zeal for mass education less, and ghostly and caste barriers would have remained as central constraints on productivity. Establishment of a New occidentalised Elite The biggest change the British made in the social social system was to replace the warlord aristocracy by an efficient bureaucracy and army. The traditional system of the eastern hemisphere India connection had been to pay its servants fairly modest salaries, and to let them add th eir income from 2 rivate transactions. This arrangement worked reasonably sanitary in front the conquest of Bengal, unless was inefficient as a way of remunerating the prescribeds of a substantial territorial reserve Empire because (a) besides oft eons of the profit went into private hands kinda than the follows coffers, and (b) an overrapacious short-term insurance was damaging to the productive capacity of the economy and likely to drive the topical anesthetic population to revolt, both of which were against the social clubs longer-term interests. Clive had operated a dual system, i. e. caller power and a puppet Nawab.Warren Hastings displaced the Nawab and took over direct administration, only if retained Indian officials. Finally, in 1785, Cornwallis haved a professional cadre of guild servants who had generous salaries, had no private trading or production interests in India, enjoyed the prospect of regular promotion and were entitled to pensions (2). All high-lev el posts were uncommunicative for the British, and Indians were excluded. Cornwallis appointed British judges, and established British officials as imposeation collectors and magistrated in each district of Bengal.From 1806 the Company trained its young recruits in Haileybury College near London. Appointments were still organized on a system of patronage, yet after 1833 the Company selected amongst its nominated candidates by competitive examination. After 1853, selection was on the unanimous on merit and the examination was thrown open to any British candidate. The examination system was influenced by the Chinese model, which had worked well for 2,000 eld and had a similar emphasis on classical learning and literary competence.The Indian civil service was therefore able to secure high lumber plurality because (a) it was very highly paid (b) it enjoyed political power which no bureaucrat could have had in Eng field. In 1829 the system was strengthened by establishing distr icts doout British India small enough to be effectively makeled by an individual British official who henceforth make outd a completely bossy power, acting as revenue collector, judge and chief of police (functions which had been tell a place stamp out the stairs the Moghul administration). This arrangement later became the cornerstone of Imperial administration byout the British Empire.As the civil service was ultimately bow to the control of the British parliament, and the British community in India was subject to close mutual surveillance, the administration was virtually incorruptible. The army of the Company was a local anesthetic aid force with 20,000-30,000 British officers and troops. It was by far the most redbrick and efficient army in Asia. After the a climbing in 1857, the size of the British contingent was raised to a third of the sum strength and all officers were British until the 1920s when a very small tote up of Indians was recruited.Normally, the t otal strength of the army was about 200,000. This army was very much smaller than those of Moghul India,3 scarce had better training and equipment, and the railroad network (which was constructed softenially for military reasons) gave it greater mobility, better logistics and intelligence. The higher ranks of the administration remained almost totally British until the 1920s when the Indian civil service examinations began to be held in India as well as the UK. 4 In 3 addition, there was a whole hierarchy of separate bureaucracies in which the higher ranks were British, i. e. he revenue, justice, police, education, medical, public works, engineering, postal and railway services as well as the provincial civil services. India thus offered highly-paid careers to an appreciable portion of the British middle and upper classes ( manicularly for its peripheral members from Scotland and Ireland). From the 1820s to the 1850s the British demonstrated a strong urge to change Indian soci al institutions, and to western sandwichize India. 5 They stamped out infanticide and ritual burning of widows (sati). They abolished slavery and eliminated dacoits (religious thugs) from the high shipway.They legalized the remarriage of widows and allowed Hindu converts to Christianity to lay claim to their share of interchangeable family property. They took steps to introduce a penal code (the code was in truth introduced in 1861) based on British law, which helped inculcate some judgments of e whole tone. to a lower place his old Hindu law, a Brahmin murderer might not be put to expiry, while a Sudra who cohabited with a high-caste cleaning lady would automatically suffer execution. downstairs the new law, Brahmin and Sudra were apt to the same punishment for the same offence (6).There was a strong running game of Benthamite radicalism in the East India Company administration (7). James Mill became a senior troupe official in 1819 after write a monumental business relati onship of India which showed a strong contempt for Indian institutions (8). From 1831 to 1836 he was the chief executive officer of the E. I. C. and his son John Stuart Mill worked for the Company from 1823 to 1858. Malthus was professor of economics at Haileybury, and the teaching there for future company officials was strongly influenced by Utilitarianism. Bentham himself was also consulted on the re wee-wee of Indian institutions.The Utilitarians purposely used India to try out experiments and intellections (e. g. competitive entry for the civil service) which they would have liked to apply in England. The Utilitarians were strong supporters of laissez-faire and abhorred any kind of state interference to promote economic development. gum olibanum they t cease to rely on market forces to cumulation with famine problems, they did nothing to stimulate market-gardening or protect effort. This laissez-faire tradition was more deeply embedded in the Indian civil service than in th e UK itself, and persisted very strongly until the late 1920s.The administration was efficient and incorruptible, but the state apparatus was of a watchdog character with few development ambitions. steady in 1936, more than half of government spgoaling was for the military, justice, police and jails, and less than 3 per cent for agriculture (9). nonpareil of the most significant things the British did to Westernize India was to introduce a modified version of English education. Macaulays 1835 Minute on didactics had a decisive impact on British educational policy and is a classic example of a Western rationalist approach to Indian civilization. out front the British took over, the Court language of the Moghuls was Persian and the Moslem population used Urdu, a mixture of Persian, Arabic and Sanskrit. Higher education was largely religious and stressed cognition of Arabic and Sanskrit. The Company had given some 4 financial support to a Calcutta Madrassa (1781), and a Sanskrit college at Benares (1792), Warren Hastings, as governor general from 1782 to 1795 had himself learned Sanskrit and Persian, and several other Company officials were oriental person scholars.One of them, Sir William Jones, had translated a great mass of Sanskrit literature and had founded the Asiatic Society of Bengal in 1785. plainly Macaulay was strongly opposed to this orientalism I believe that the hand system t halts, not to accelerate the progress of truth, but to delay the natural death of expiring errors. We are a Board for wasting public money, for printing books which are less value than the paper on which they are printed was while it was leisure for giving artificial move onment to soused history, absurd metaphysics, absurd physics, absurd theology I have no knowledge of either Sanskrit or Arabic But I have done what I could to form a correct pronounce of their value Who could deny that a one shelf of a serious European library was worth the whole native literat ure of India and Arabia all the historical information which has been collected from all the books written in the Sanskrit language is less valuable than what whitethorn be found in the most paltry abridgements used at preparative schools in England. For these reasons Macaulay had no hesitation in deciding in favour of English education, but it was not to be for the masses It is im workable for us, with our limited heart to attempt to educate the body of the people.We must at present do our best to form a class who may be interpreters betwixt us and the megs whom we govern a class of persons, Indian in blood and colour, but English in taste, in opinions, in morals, and in intellect. To that class we may leave it to refine the vernacular dialects of the country, to enrich those dialects with terms of science borrowed from the Western nomenclature, and to render them by legs fit vehicles for conveying knowledge to the great mass of the population (10). Until 1857 it was possib le to entertain the view (as Marx id) that the British may eventually destroy traditional Indian society and Westernize the country (11). But activist Westernizing policies and the attempt to extend British rule by taking over native states whose rulers had left no heirs provoked sections of both the Hindu and Muslim communities into rebellion in the Mutiny of 1857. Although the Mutiny was successfully put down with substantial help from loyal Indian troops including the recently conquered Sikhs, British policy towards Indian institutions and society became much more conservative. The Crown took over direct responsibility and the East India Company was disbanded.The Indian civil service attracted fewer people with innovating ideas than had the East India Company and was more closely controlled from London. The British forged an alliance with the remaining native princes and stopped taking over new territory. Until the end of their rule about a quarter of the Indian population remai ned in quasiautonomous native states. These had official British residents but were fairly free in internal policy, and the effort of Westernization came to a standstill. 5 The education system which developed was a very pale reflection of that in the UK.Three universities were set up in 1857 in Calcutta, Madras and Bombay, but they were merely examining bodies and did no teaching. Higher education was carried out in affiliated colleges which gave a two- grade B. A. mannequin with heavy emphasis on rote learning and examinations. Drop-out ratios were always very high. They did little to promote analytic capacity or independent thinking and produced a group of graduates with a half-baked knowledge of English, but sufficiently Westernized to be alienated from their own culture. 12 It was not until the 1920s that Indian universities provided teaching facilities and then and for M. A. tudents. Furthermore, Indian education was of a predominantly literacy character and the provision f or technical foul training was much less than in any European country. Education for girls was almost totally ignored throughout the nineteenth speed of light. Because higher education was in English, there was no official effort to translate Western literature into the vernacular, nor was there any standardization of Indian scripts whose variety is a major barrier to multi-lingualism amongst educated Indians. Primary education was not taken very seriously as a government obligation and was financed largely by the weak local authorities.As a result, the great mass of the population had no access to education and, at freedom in 1947, 88 per cent were illiterate. Progress was accelerated from the thirty-something onwards, but at independence only a fifth of children were receiving any prim upary schooling. Education could have played a major role in encouraging social mobility, eliminating religious superstition, increasing productivity, and uplifting the status of women. Instead it was used to one shot a tiny elite into imitation Englishmen and a somewhat larger group into government clerks. Having failed to Westernize India, the British established themselves as a separate ruling caste.Like other Indian castes, they did not intermarry or eat with the lower (native) castes. Thanks to the British public-school system, their children were shipped off and did not fuse with the natives. At the end of their professional careers they returned home. The small creole class of Anglo-Indians were outcastes otiose to integrate into Indian or local British society (13). The British kept to their clubs and bungalows in special suburbs known as cantonments and civil lines. They keep the Moghul tradition of official pomp, sumptuary residences, and retinues of servants (14).They did not adopt the Moghul custom of polygamy, but remained monogamous and brought in their own women. Society became prim and priggish (15). The British ruled India in much the same way as the Roman consuls had ruled in Africa 2,000 socio-economic classs earlier, and were very advised of the Roman paradigm. The elite with its classical education and contempt for business were kind of happy establishing law and order, and keeping barbarians at bay on the confines of the raj. 16 They developed their own brand of self-righteous arrogance, considering themselves purveyors not of universal but of mature government.For them the word British lost its geographic connotation and became an gens signifying moral rectitude. 6 The striking thing about the British raj is that it was operated by so few people. There were only 31,000 British in India in 1805 (of which 22,000 were in the army and 2,000 in civil government) (17). The number add-ond preferously after the Mutiny, but thereafter remained steady. In 1911, there were 164,000 British (106,000 employed, of which 66,000 were in the army and police and 4,000 in civil government) (18). In 1931, there were 168,000 (90,000 em ployed, 60,000 in the army and police and 4,000 in civil overnment). They were a thinner horizontal surface than the Muslim rulers had been (never more than 0. 05 per cent of the population). Because of the small size of the administration and its philosophy of minimal government responsibility outside the field of law and order, India ended the compound effect with a very low level of valuateation. The British had inherited the Moghul taxation system which provided a land revenue equal to 15 per cent of national income, but by the end of the colonial limit land tax was only 1 per cent of national income and the total tax burden was only 6 per cent.It is rum that this large reduction in the fiscal burden has passed almost without causerie in the literature on Indian economic history. 19 On the contrary, emphasis is usually place on the heaviness of the tax burden, e. g. by D. Naoroji and R. C. Dutt. Most of the benefits of the lower fiscal burden were felt by landlords, and were not passed on to the mass of the population. In urban domains new classes emerged under British rule, i. e. industrial capitalists and a new bourgeoisie of bureaucrats, lawyers, doctors, teachers and journalists whose social position was out-of-pocket to education and training rather than heredity.In the princely states, the remnants of the Moghul aristocracy continued their extravagances large palaces, harems, hordes of retainers, miniature armies, ceremonial elephants, tiger hunts, and stables full of Rolls Royces. Agriculture The colonial government made institutional changes in agriculture by transforming traditionally circumscribed property rights into something more closely resembling the unencumbered private property characteristic of Western capitalism. The beneficiaries of these new rights varied in different part of India.The top layer of Moghul property, the jagir, was abolished ( however in the autonomous princely states), and the bulk of the old warlord aristoc racy was dispossessed. Their previous income from land revenue, and that of the Moghul state, was now appropriated by the British as land tax. However, in the Bengal presidency (i. e. modern Bengal, Bihar, Orissa and part of Madras) the second layer of Moghul property rights belonging to Moghul tax collectors (zamindars) was reinforced (20). All zamindars in these champaigns now had hereditary status, so long as they paid their land taxes, and their judicial and administrative functions disappeared (21).In the Moghul intent the zamindars had usually kept a tenth of the land revenue to themselves, but by the end of British rule their income from rents was a multiple of the tax they paid to the state. In Bihar, for instance, five-sixths of the total sum levied by 1950 was rent and only one-sixth revenue (22). 7 However, zamindars were not really the equivalent of Western landowners. Dominant families in each village remained as their tenants-in-chief and continued to enjoy galore(p ostnominal) of the old customary rights, i. e. they could not be evicted, their rights were heritable and their term of a contract payments could not be raised easily.Lower-caste families were usually sub-tenants of the tenants-in-chief, rather than direct tenants of the zamindars. much there were several layers of tenancy between the actual cultivator and the zamindar. Sub-tenants had less security and less defence against rack-renting than tenants-in-chief. It is worth noting that when zamindari rights were abolished around 1952 and the old zamindar letting income was converted into state revenue, the nub involved was only about 2 per cent of farm income in the relevant fields of India.This suggests that by the end of the colonial period, the zamindars were not able to squeeze as much surplus out of their chief tenants as is sometimes suggested. The typical zamindari estate at the end of British rule seems to have been very different from that at the end of the eighteenth cent ury. In Bengal the total number of landowners which did not exceed c in the beginning of Hastings administration in 1772, rose in the course of a century to 154,200. In 1872 there were 154,200 estates of which 533, or 0. 34 per cent, only are great properties with an area of 20,000 acres and upwards 15,747, or 10. 1 per cent, range from 500 to 20,000 acres in area while the number of estates which feral short of 500 acres is no less than 137,920, or 89. 44 per cent, of the whole (23). Misra attributes this fall in the average size of zamindari properties to the fact that they could be inherited or interchange freely, whereas the Moghul state treasured to keep the number small because zamindars had administrative functions under the Moghul Empire. Under the British, transfers became much more frequent, particularly into the hands of moneylenders.The moneylenders are frequently presented as squeezing out poor peasants and tenantry and thus promoting the concentration of riches, b ut the express of what happened to zamindar estates suggests that village moneylenders may also have helped to break up concentrations of wealth (24). In the Madras and Bombay Presidencies, which intered most of Southern India, the British dispossessed many of the old Moghul and Mahratta nobility and big zamindars, and vested property rights and tax obligations in individual peasants.This settlement was known as the ryotwari (peasant tenure) system. However, the term peasant is misleading, because most of those who acquired land titles belonged to the traditionally dominant castes in villages. Lower-caste cultivators became their tenants. Thus there was no change in social structure at the village level, except that the new ownership rights gave greater opportunities for sale and mortgage, and the security of the tenant was less than it had been under the previous system. The change in legal status was limited by several factors.First of all, illiterate peasant did not always see the new situation, and there were strong social ties in the joint family and the caste panchayats to prevent major deviations from old habits Secondly, the new administration was rather external from 8 individual villages (with a district officer responsible for over a thousand villages), and many British administrators had a personal parti pris in favour of customary tenant rights because by maintaining them they could avoid political trouble. At a later stage, the government itself introduced a good deal of legislation to protect customary rights in response to peasant disturbances. 5 Land policy was, therefore, another(prenominal)(prenominal) instance of British policy of halfWesternization. The change from custom to contract was not nearly as sharp as that brought about in lacquer by the Meiji land reforms. The British were more concerned with arrangements which would guarantee their revenue and not provoke too much political disturbance rather than in increasing productivity or introducing capitalist institutions. The Utilitarians who dominated the Company from 1820 to 1850 would have liked to push in this direction, but they were displaced at mid-century by the paternalist conservatives f the Imperial raj.Nevertheless, there were some economic consequences of the new legal situation. Because of the emergence of clear titles, it was now possible to mortgage land. The status of moneylenders was also improved by the change from Muslim to British law. There had been moneylenders in the Moghul period, but their importance grew comfortably under British rule, and over time a considerable amount of land changed hands through foreclosures (26). Over time, two forces raised the income of landowners. One of these was the increasing scarcity of land as population expanded. This raised land values and rents.The second was the decline in the incidence of land tax. Indian literature usually stresses the heavy burden of land tax in the early days of British rule, b ut the fact that it fell advantageously over time is seldom noted (27). The Moghul land tax was about 30 per cent of the crop, but by 1947 land tax was only 2 per cent of agricultural income. The fall was most tag in Bengal where the tax was fixed in perpetuity in 1793, but it was also neat in other areas. As a result of these changes, there was not only an increase in village income but a widening of income inequality within villages.The village squirearchy current relatively higher incomes because of the reduced burden of land tax and the increase in rents tenants and agricultural labourers may well have experienced a decline in income because their traditional rights were curtailed and their bargaining power was reduced by land scarcity. The class of landless agricultural labourers grew in size under British rule, but modern scholarship has shown that they were not a excogitation of the British (28). They were about 15 per cent of the rural population at the end of the eight eenth century, and about a quarter of the labour force now.Although these were outstanding modifications in the village structure, the traditional hierarchy of caste was not destroyed. Income differentials widened, but the social and ritual hierarchy in villages did not change its character. Village society was not egalitarian in Moghul times, and in most cases those whose income rose in the British period were already socially dominant, although there were exceptions (29). Recent sociological studies, although they indicate 9 changes in the British period, also portray a village hierarchy in the forties and 1950s which cannot be very different from that in the Moghul period (30).We still find a dominant caste of petty landlords, an mediocre group of tenants, village artisans tied by jajmani relationships, a group of low-status labourers, untouchable menials with the whole held together by the same elaborate system of caste. One might have evaluate the legal changes introduced b y the British to have had a positive effect on efficiency. They removed the class of jagirdars who had no incentive to invest in agriculture, and gave land rights to rural capitalists who could buy and sell land fairly freely and enjoy an increasing portion of the product.Moneylenders helped to ancestry out improvident or inefficient landowners. However, most farmers were illiterate and the government did not provide research or extension services, or encourage the use of fertilizers. Until recently, with the arrival of the tubewell, there were technical limits to the possibility of small-scale irrigation. There were also organizational difficulties in changing technique to improve productivity. The department of labour in the village and hereditary attitudes to work as a semi-religious ritual rather than a means to improve income were obstacles to change.Furthermore, a good many of the cultivating landowners whose income was change magnitude were relatively poor and used their i ncreased income for economic inhalation rather than investment. Some of those who were better off probably improved their land or took over waste land, but as religion inculcated the idea that manual labour was polluting, some of them probably worked less (31). The big zamindars used some of their extra income to develop waste land, but many complaisant a life style rather like the old Moghul aristocracy and had a high propensity to consume. According to Raychaudhuri, a zamindars raise with a hundred rooms was not exceptional.Some of the enterp come up ones probably transferred their savings out of agriculture into trade and effort or bought their children a Western-type education. Thus the effect of the change was to increase productivity and savings, but not much. During the period of British rule, agricultural production grew substantially in order to feed a population which grew from 165 million in 1757 to 420 million in 1947. The new system of land ownership offered some c omment to increase produce, and there was substantial waste land available for development. The colonial government made some contribution towards increased make through irrigation.The irrigated area was increased about eightfold, and eventually more than a quarter of the land of British India was irrigated. 33 Irrigation was extended both as a source of revenue and as a measure against famine. A good deal of the irrigation work was in the Punjab and Sind. The motive here was to provide land for retired Indian army personnel, many of whom came from the Punjab, and to build up population in an area which bordered on the disputed frontier with Afghanistan. These areas, which had formerly been desert, became the biggest irrigated area in the world and a major producer of wheat nd cotton fiber, both for merchandise and for sale in other parts of India. 10 Apart from government investment in irrigation, there was a substantial private investment, and by the end of British rule privat e irrigation investment covered nearly 25 million acres of British India. Improvements in send off facilities (particularly railways, but also steamships and the Suez canal) helped agriculture by permitting some degree of specialization on cash crops. This increased yields somewhat, but the bulk of the country stuck to subsistence farming. Plantations were developed for indigo, sugar, jute and tea.These items made a significant contribution to exports, but in the context of Indian agriculture as a whole, they were not very definitive. In 1946, the two primary staples, tea and jute, were less than 3. 5 per cent of the gross value of crop output. 34 Thus the enlargement of markets through international trade was less of a stimulus in India than in other Asian countries such as Ceylon, Burma or Thailand (35). Little was done to promote agricultural technology. There was some improvement in seeds, but no extension service, no improvement in livestock and no official encouragement to u se fertilizer.Lord Mayo, the Governor General, said in 1870, I do not know what is precisely meant by ammoniac manure. If it means guano, superphosphate or any other artificial product of that kind, we might as well ask the people of India to manure their ground with champagne (36). Statistics are not available on agricultural output for the low century and a half of British rule, but all the indications suggest that there was substantial growth. We do not know whether output rose swift or more slowly than population, but it seems likely that the movements were roughly parallel.For the locomote half century of British rule, the main calculations of output are those by George Blyn. His head start study, which has been widely quoted, was promulgated in 1954 by the National Income social unit of the Indian government and showed only a 3 per cent increase in crop output in British India from 1893 to 1946, i. e. a period in which population increased 46 per cent His second study, pu blished in 1966 showed a 16. 6 per cent increase, and this, too, has been widely quoted, but he also gives a modified series which shows a 28. 9 per cent increase.This seems preferable, as the official figures on rice yields in Orissa, which are corrected in his modified estimate, seem obviously in error. However, even Blyns upper estimate is probably an understatement because he shows a very small increase in acreage. It is difficult to believe that per capita food output could have gone down as much as he suggests, whilst waste land remained unused. There has been a very big increase in the cultivated area since independence and it seems likely that the increase in the preceding half century was bigger than Blyn suggests.Therefore, my own estimate of crop output (Appendix B) for 1900-46, uses Blyns figures on yields but assumes that the cultivated area rose by 23 per cent (Sivasubramonians figure) rather than by 12. 2 per cent (Blyns figure) (37). My estimate shows agricultural ou tput travel about the same amount as population from 1900 to 1946. However, even this may be too low. The basic reports on areas under cultivation are those provided by village accountants 11 (patwaris) in areas where land revenue was periodically changed, and by village watchmen (chowkidars) in areas where the land revenue was permanently settled.There was some incentive for farmers to gift patwaris to under-report land for tax purposes, and chowkidars are all too often illiterate and drowsy people, who would usually report that things were normal, i. e. the same as the year in the first place. There is, therefore, a tendency for under-reporting of both levels and rates of growth in areas covered by statistics, and the areas not covered by statistics were more often than not on the margin of cultivation and may have had a more steeply rising trend than the average area covered.Thus Blyn shows no growth in output in Bengal where the chowkidars did the basic reporting. He did not cover the Sind desert area in which the British built the huge Sukkur assault in 1932. Blyn was, of course, aware of these difficulties and tried to correct for them as far as possible, but the fundamental problems are not amenable to statistical manipulation but require hunch adjustment.My own conclusion from the evidence available is that agricultural output per head was at least as high at the end of British rule as it was in the Moghul period, and that rural consumption levels were somewhat higher because of the lower tax burden on agriculture, and the smaller degree of wastage which allowed surplus areas to sell their grains. This slight improvement in standards may have contributed to the expansion in population. However, agricultural yields and nutritional levels at independence were amongst the lowest in the world. Under British rule, the Indian population remained subject to recurrent famines and epidemic diseases.In 1876-8 and 1899-1900 famine killed millions of people. In the nineties there was a widespread outbreak of bubonic plague and in 1919 a great influenza epidemic. It is sometimes asserted by Indian nationalist historians that British policy increased the incidence of famine in India, particularly in the nineteenth century (38). Unfortunately we do not have any figures on agricultural production for this period, and it is difficult to base a public opinion merely on catalogues of famine years whose intensity we cannot measure. As agriculture was extended to more marginal land one would have expected output to become more volatile.But this was offset to a considerable accomplishment by the major improvement in transport brought by railways, and the greater security of water supply brought by irrigation. It is noteworthy that the decades in which famines occurred were ones in which population was static rather than falling. 39 In the 1920s and 1930s there were no famines, and the 1944 famine in Bengal was due to war conditions and transpo rt difficulties rather than crop failure. However, the greater stability after 1920 may have been partly due to a lucky break in the stomach cycle40 rather than to a new stability of agriculture.British rule reduced some of the old checks on Indian population growth. The main contribution was the closing of internal warfare and local banditry. There was some reduction in the incidence of famine. The death rate was also reduced to some degree by making ritual suicide and infanticide illegal. The British contributed to public wellness by introducing smallpox vaccination, establishing Western medicine and training modern doctors, by killing rats, and establishing 12 quarantine physical processs. As a result, the death rate fell and the population of India grew by 1947 to more than two-and-a-half times its size in 1757.Industry Several Indian authors have argued that British rule led to a de-industrialization of India. R. C. Dutt argued, India in the eighteenth century was a great ma nufacturing as well as a great agricultural country, and the products of the Indian loom supplied the markets of Asia and Europe. It is, unfortunately, true that the East India Company and the British Parliament, following the selfish commercial-grade policy of a hundred years ago, discouraged Indian devisers in the early years of British rule in order to encourage the rising manufactures of England.Their fixed policy, pursued during the last decades of the eighteenth century and the first decades of the nineteenth, was to make India subservient to the industries of Great Britain, and to make the Indian people grow rude produce only, in order to supply material for the looms and manufactories of Great Britain (41). R. Palme Dutt, writing forty years later, argued that the process had been continuous the real picture of modern India is a picture of what has been aptly called de-industrializationthat is, the decline of the old handicraft exertion without the compensating advance o f modern industry.The advance of factory industry has not overtaken the descent of handicraft. The process of decay characteristic of the nineteenth century has been carried forward in the twentieth century and in the post-war period (42). Nehru, in his popular history is a conflation of the two Dutts, argued that the British deindustrialized India, and that this is the real the fundamental cause of the grand poverty of the Indian people, and it is of comparatively recent origin (43).There is a good deal of truth in the deindustrialization argument. Moghul India did have a bigger industry than any other country which became a European colony, and was unequalled in being an industrial exporter in pre-colonial times. A large part of the Moghul industry was destroyed in the course of British rule. However, it is important to understand precisely how this deindustrialization came about and to try to get some idea of its quantitative significance in different periods.Oversimplified ex planations, which exaggerate the role of British commercial policy and ignore the role of changes in take in and technology, have been very common and have had some indecorous impact on post-independence economic policy (44). Between 1757 and 1857 the British wiped out the Moghul court, and eliminated threequarters of the warlord aristocracy (all except those in princely states). They also eliminated more than half of the local chiefs (zamindars) and in their place established a bureaucracy with European tastes. The new rulers wore European stuffes and shoes, drank merchandise beer, wines and spirits, and used European weapons.Their tastes were copied by the manful members of the new Indian middle class which arose to act as their clerks and intermediaries. As a result of these political and social 13 changes, about three-quarters of the domestic demand for sumptuousness handicrafts was destroyed. This was a shattering blow to manufacturers of fine muslins, jewellery, extravag ance clothes and footwear, decorative swords and weapons. It is not known how important these items were in national income, but my own guess would be that the home market for these goods was about 5 per cent of Moghul national income. The export market was probably another 1. per cent of national income, and most of this market was also lost. There was a reduction of European demand because of the change in sartorial tastes after the French renewing, and the greatly reduced price of more ordinary materials because of the revolution of textile technology in England. The second blow to Indian industry came from massive imports of bald-faced textiles from England after the Napoleonic wars. In the period 1896-1913, imported effect goods supplied about 60 per cent of Indian cloth consumption,45 and the simile was probably higher for most of the nineteenth century.Home spinning, which was a spare-time activity of village women, was greatly reduced. A large proportion of village han d-loom weavers must have been displaced, though many switched to using factory instead of home-spun yarn. Even as late as 1940 a third of Indian piece goods were produced on hand looms (46). The new manufactured textile goods were considerably cheaper (47) and of better quality than hand-loom products, so their advent increased textile consumption. At the end of British rule, there can be no doubt that cloth consumption per head was substantially larger than in the Moghul period.We do not know how big an increase in textile consumption occurred, but if per capita consumption of cotton cloth doubled (which seems quite plausible), then the switching effect on hand-loom weavers would have been smaller than at first appears. The hand-loom weavers who produced a third of output in 1940 would have been producing two-thirds if there had been no increase in per capita consumption. In time, India built up her own textile manufacturing industry which displaced British imports. But there was a gap of several decades before manufacturing started and a period of 130 years before British textile imports were eliminated.India could probably have copied Lancashires technology more quickly if she had been allowed to impose a protective tariff in the way that was done in the ground forces and France in the first few decades of the nineteenth century, but the British impose a policy of free trade. British imports entered India duty free, and when a small tariff was required for revenue purposes Lancashire pressure led to the imposition of a corresponding excise duty on Indian products to prevent them gaining a competitive advantage. This undoubtedly handicapped industrial development.If India had been politically independent, her tax structure would probably have been different. In the 1880s, Indian customs revenues were only 2. 2 per cent of the trade turnover, i. e. the lowest ratio in any country. In Brazil, by contrast, import duties at that period were 21 per cent of tra de turnover. 48 If India had enjoyed protection there is no doubt that its textile industry would have started earlier and grown sudden. 14 The first textile mill were started in the 1850s by Indian capitalists who had made their money trading with the British and had acquired some education in English.Cotton textiles were launched in Bombay with financial and managerial help from British trading companies. India was the first country in Asia to have a modern textile industry, preceding Japan by twenty years and China by forty years. Cotton mills were started in Bombay in 1851, and they concentrated on coarse yarns sold domestically and to China and Japan yarn exports were about half of output. Modern jute manufacturing started about the same time as cotton textiles. The first jute mill was built in 1854 and the industry expanded rapidly in the vicinity of Calcutta. The industry was largely in the hands of foreigners (mainly Scots).Between 1879 and 1913 the number of jute spindles rose tenfold much faster than growth in the cotton textile industry. The jute industry was able to expand faster than cotton textiles because its sales did not depend so heavily on the povertystricken domestic markets. Most of jute output was for export. Coal mining, mainly in Bengal, was another industry which achieved significance. Its output, which by 1914 had reached 15. 7 million tons, largely met the demands of the Indian railways. In 1911 the first Indian steel mill was built by the Tata Company at Jamshedpur in Bihar.However, production did not take place on a significant scale before the First earthly concern War. The Indian steel industry started fifteen years later than in China, where the first steel mill was built at Hangyang in 1896. The first Japanese mill was built in 1898. In both China and Japan the first steel mills (and the first textile mills) were government efforts. Indian firms in industry, insurance and banking were given a boost from 1905 onwards by the swadeshi movement, which was a nationalist boycott of British goods in favour of Indian enterprise.During the First World War, wish of British imports strengthened the hold of Indian firms on the home market for textiles and steel. After the war, under nationalist pressure, the government started to favour Indian enterprise in its purchase of stores and it agreed to create a tariff commission in 1921 which started raising tariffs for protective reasons. By 1925, the average tariff level was 14 per cent49 compared with 5 per cent pre-war. The procedure for fixing tariffs was lengthy and tariff protection was granted more quick to foreign-owned than to Indian firms, but in the 1930s protection was sharply increased (50).The government was more willing to protect the textile industry when the menace came from Japan and not the UK. Between 1930 and 1934 the tariff on cotton cloth was raised from 11 to 50 per cent, although British imports were accorded a margin of preference. As a re sult of these measures, there was considerable substitution of local textiles for imports. In 1896, Indian mills supplied only 8 per cent of total cloth consumption in 1913, 20 per cent in 1936, 62 per cent and in 1945, 76 per cent (51). By the latter date there were no imports of piece goods. 15Until the end of the Napoleonic wars, cotton manufactures had been Indias main export. They reached their posting in 1798, and in 1813 they still amounted to ? 2 million, but thereafter they fell rapidly (52). Thirty years later, half of Indian imports were cotton textiles from Manchester. This kick in in Indias main export caused a problem for the Company, which had to find ways to convert its rupee revenue into resources transferable to the UK. The Company therefore promoted exports of raw materials on a larger scale, including sugar, silk, saltpetre and indigo, and greatly increased exports of opium which were traded against Chinese tea.These dopepeddling efforts provoked the Anglo-Chin ese war of 1842, after which access to the Chinese market was greatly widened. By the middle of the nineteenth century opium was by far the biggest export of India, and remained in this position until the 1880s when its relative and absolute importance began to decline. Another new export was raw cotton, which could not compete very well in European markets against higher quality American and Egyptian cottons, (except during the US Civil War), but found a market in Japan and China.Sugar exports were built up after 1833 when the abolition of slavery raised West Indian production costs, but India had no long-run comparative advantage in sugar exports. Indigo (used to dye textiles) was an important export until the 1890s when it was hit by competition from German synthetic dyes. The jute industry boomed from the time of the Crimean War onwards, when the UK stopped importing flax from Russia. In addition to raw jute (shipped for manufacture in Dundee) India exported jute manufactures. Grain exports were also built up on a sizeable scale, mainly from the newly irrigated area of the Punjab.The tea industry was introduced to India from China and built up on a orchard basis. Tea exports became important from the 1860s onwards. Hides and skins and oil cake (used as animal feed and fertilizer) were also important raw material exports. Table 3-1 Level of Asian Exports f. o. b. 1850-1950 (million dollars) 1850 1913 1937 1950 Ceylon 5 76 124 328 China 24 294 516 (700) India 89 786 717 1,178 Indonesia 24 270 550 800 Japan 1 354 1,207 820 Malaya 24 193 522 1,312 Philippines n. a. 48 153 331 Thailand 3 43 76 304 Figures refer to customs area of the year concerned.In 1850 and 1913 the Indian area included Burma. The comparability of 1937 and 1950 figures is affected by the separation of Pakistan. Manufactured textile exports form India began to increase in the 1850s when the first modern mills were established. The bulk of exports were yarn and crude piece goods which were s old in China and Japan. As the Chinese and Japanese were prevented by colonial-type treaties from 16 imposing tariffs for manufactured imports they were wide open to Indian goods, and particularly cotton textiles and yarn.Indian jute manufactures were exported mainly to Europe and the USA However, India began to suffer from Japanese competition in the 1890s. Indian yarn exports to Japan dropped sharply from 8,400 tons in 1890 to practically nothing in 1898, and India also suffered from Japanese competition in China. The Japanese set up factories in China after the Sino-Japanese War of 1894-5. Before this, India had supplied 96 per cent of Chinese yarn imports, the UK 4 per cent, and Japan none. Within three years the Japanese were supplying a quarter to Chinese imports, and by 1914 India was exporting less yarn to China than was Japan.During the First World War Japan made further progress in the Chinese market and by 1924 supplied threequarters of Chinese imports. By 1928 India was exporting only 3 per cent of her yarn output. By the end of the 1930s, Indian exports of yarn to China and Japan had disappeared, piece goods exports had fallen off, and India imported both yarn and piece goods from China and Japan. Indian exports grew fairly rapidly in the period up to 1913, but their growth was slower than that of most other Asian countries which had a natural resource endowment offering greater opportunities for trade.As a consequence, in 1913, India had a smaller trade per head than most countries except China. Nevertheless, exports were 10. 7 per cent of national income, probably a higher ratio than has been reached before or since. Until 1898 India, like most Asian countries, was on the silver standard. In the 1870s the price of silver began to fall and the rupee depreciated against sterling. This led to some rise in the internal price level, but it helped to make Indian exports more competitive with those of the UK, e. g. in the Chinese textile market.In 189 8, India adopted a metal(prenominal) exchange standard which tied the rupee to sterling at a fixed value of 15 to 1. This weakened her competitiveness vis-a-vis China which remained on a depreciating silver standard, but its potential adverse effects were mitigated because Japan went on to the gold exchange standard at the same time. During the First World War, when the sterling exchange rate was allowed to float, the rupee appreciated. Unfortunately, when sterling resumed a fixed (and overvalued) parity in 1925, the rupee exchange rate was fixed above the pre-war level.This overreckoning eased the fiscal problems of government in making transfers to the UK and enabled British residents in India, or those on Indian pensions in the UK, to get more sterling for their rupees, but it made it necessary for domestic economic policy to be deflationary (in case wages) and greatly hindered Indian exports, particularly those to or competing with China and Japan. As a result, Indian exports fell from 1913 to 1937, a poorer performance than that of almost any other country.At independence exports were less than 5 per cent of national income. If we look at Indian export performance from 1850 to 1950 it was worse than that of any other country 17 in Asia (see Table 3-1). The Second World War gave a fillip to Indian industrial output, but there was not much increase in capacity because of the difficulty of importing capital goods and the lack of a domestic capital goods industry. Many of the most lucrative commercial, financial, business and plantation jobs in the modern sector were occupied by foreigners.Although the East India Companys legally enforced monopoly privileges were ended in 1833, the British continued to exercise effective dominance through the system of managing agencies. These agencies, originally set up by former employees of the East India Company, were used both to manage industrial enterprise and to handle most of Indias international trade. They were closely linked with British banks, insurance and shipping companies. Managing agencies had a quasi-monopoly in access to capital, and they had interlocking directorships which gave them control over supplies and markets (53).They dominated the foreign markets in Asia. They had better access to government officials than did Indians. The agencies were in many ways able to take decisions favourable to their own interests rather than those of shareholders. They were paid commissions based on gross profits or total sales and were often agents for the raw materials used by the companies they managed. Thus the Indian capitalists who did emerge were highly dependent on British commercial capital and many sectors of industry were dominated by British firms, e. . shipping, banking, insurance, coal, plantation crops and jute. Indian industrial efficiency was hampered by the British administrations neglect of technical education, and the reluctance of British firms and managing agencies to prov ide training of managerial experience to Indians. Even in the Bombay textile industry, where most of the capital was Indian, 28 per cent of the managerial and supervisory staff were British in 1925 (42 per cent in 1895) and the British component was even bigger in more complex industries.This course raised Indian production costs (54). At lower levels there was widespread use of jobbers for hiring workers and maintaining discipline, and workers themselves were a completely unskilled group who had to bribe the jobbers to get and retain their jobs. There were also problems of race, language and caste distinctions between management, supervisors and workers (55). The small size and very diversified output of the enterprises hindered efficiency.It is partly for these reasons (and the overvaluation of the currency) that Indian exports had difficulty in competing with Japan. The basic limitations on the growth of industrial output were the natural poverty of the rural population, and the fact that a large proportion of the elite had a taste for imported goods or exported their purchase power. The government eventually provided tariff protection but did not itself create industrial plants, sponsor development banks, or give preference to local industry in allotting contracts.The banking system gave little help to industry and technical education was poor. Most of these things changed when India became independent except the first and most important, i. e. the extreme poverty of the rural population which limited the expansion of the 18 market for industrial goods. By the time of independence, large-scale factory industry in India employed less than 3 million people as compared with 12 1/4 million in small-scale industry and handicrafts, and a labour force of 160 million. 6 This may appear meagre, but Indias per capita industrial output at independence was higher than elsewhere in Asia outside Japan, and more than half of Indias exports were manufactures. British po licy was less restrictive to local industry than that of other colonial power, and had permitted the emergence of a small but powerful class of Indian entrepreneurs. It should be noted, however, that modern industry was heavily concentrated in Calcutta, Bombay and Ahmedabad. The area which was to become Pakistan had practically no industry at all.Table 3-2 Industrial Growth in the Last half Century of British Rule Small-scale enterprise Employment rank added (thousands) (million 1938 rupees) 1900/1901 13,308 2,296 1945/1946 12,074 2,083 Factory establishments Employment Value added (thousands) (million 1938 rupees) 601 379 2,983 2,461 Source S. Sivasubramonian, op. cit. , for employment and value added in factories. For small-scale enterprise I assume value added to move pro rata to employment. In the last half century of British rule the output of factory industry rose about six-fold (about 4. per cent a year) whereas the output of small-scale industry declined. Their joint outp ut rose about two-thirds (1. 2 per cent a year), and per head of population, joint output was rising by 0. 4 per cent a year. We know that output in the modern factory sector was zero in 1850, and if we assume that small enterprise output grew parallel with population from 1850 to 1900, then total industrial output would have grown by 0. 8 per cent a year in this period, or about 0. 3 per cent a year per head of population. Some increase seems plausible in this period of railway development and expanding international trade.It therefore seems possible that in the last century of British rule, per capita output of industrial goods rose by a third. But in the first century of British rule, i. e. 17571857, it seems certain that industrial output fell per head of population because (a) the home and domestic market for luxury goods was cut so drastically (b) the home market for yarn and cheap cloth was invaded by foreign competition. Over the whole period of British rule it therefore see ms likely that industrial output per head of the population was not significantly changed.The Economic Burden of Foreign Rule The major burden of foreign rule arose from the fact that the British raj was a regime of expatriates. Under an Indian administration, income from government service would have accrued to the local inhabitants and not to foreigners. The diversion of upper-class income into the hands of foreigners 19 inhibited the development of local industry because it put purchasing power into the hands of people with a taste for foreign goods. This increased imports and was particularly damaging to the luxury handicraft industries.Another important effect of foreign rule on the long-run growth potential of the economy was the fact that a large part of its potential savings were siphoned abroad. This drain of funds from India to the UK has been a point of major quarrel between Indian nationalist historians and defenders of the British raj. However, the only real ground fo r controversy are statistical. There can be no defensive structure that there was a substantial outflow which lasted for 190 years. If these funds had been invested in India they could have made a significant contribution to raising income levels.The first generation of British rulers was rapacious. Clive took quarter of a million pounds

No comments:

Post a Comment